PHRYGIA, FINANCE, AND FRONT MAN
The Assyrian conquests must have released a very flood of bullion on to the
markets of the Middle East. Steeply rising prices that would have followed
must have made it more profitable for bankers and money lenders and
manufacturers from this most ancient area to look further afield for lands
where money as denoted by treasure was not so plentiful, and therefore
wherein such treasure might serve them best.
The gold, silver, and electrum
bullion with which, after 671 B.C. and the Assyrian thrust into Egypt during
the second phase of Assyrian conquest, their store houses and strong rooms
were overflowing, could be put to better use than lying inactive in these
same store houses or strong rooms, at Nineveh, Babylon, Lagash, or Ur or
wherever they were situated.
The privately issued electrum staters of Lydia of the seventh and sixth
century B.C. denoted a highly significant possibility...
Lydia was the
source of something Assyria badly needed. The first thing such military
organization such as existed in Assyria would need, would be financial
organization, and secondly, stemming from its financial organization,
organization above all towards the purpose of the purchase of the best of
arms... Phrygia was famous throughout the ancient world for its arms. (1)
Lydia bordered on and indeed may very well have been part of Phrygia in
earlier times. Hence the secret of the electrum staters. Assyria needed
Phrygian arms and at the same time had to accept such financial terns as the
suppliers of such arms decreed, and it may safely be assured that such terms
stipulated payment was to be made in gold, silver, or electrum.
The extraordinary treasure of such as Sadyattes, latter dispossessed and
executed by Croesus, cannot be explained any other way. It had to derive
from the plunder gathered up by Assyria from all its conquests, as much as
from the river washings of Lydia. The evidence of the gold artifacts, of the
ancient civilizations of Anatolia of thousands of years previous to this
time, such as Hacilar, Catal Huyuk, Dorak, (2) would indicate that the
Anatolian rivers had been well washed for gold many ages before (3)...
Although according to the Guide to the principal coins of the Greeks
published by the British Museum, pages 12-13, electrum for the Lydian
coinages came from the Pactolus river, the question still stands: "what
happened to the enormous gold, silver, and electrum plunder, of Assyria;
that had been taken from Aram, Israel, Arabia, and above all from Egypt?"
The great temple cities such as Karnak must have literally gleamed with gold
and silver monuments and finishing. According to Diodorus in 57 B.C.:
"So
that there was no city under the sun so adorned with so many and stately
monuments of gold, silver, and ivory, and multitudes of colossi and
obelisks, each cut out of an entire stone...
...The decorations of these buildings were as magnificent as their design.
The walls and pylons were covered with paintings and sculpture, the gates
and pillars were overlaid with gold and the floors with silver, which, to
the Egyptians was a metal hardly less precious than gold itself." (4)
The electrum obelisks of Hatsepsut (5) as removed by Ashurbanipal from
before the Temple of Amon at Karnak in 661 B.C., contained, according to
Breasted 2500 talents of electrum, (6) and according to other writers as
much as 2900 talent; not to speak of other more massive plunder stripped
from temple and tomb.
The electrum from the obelisks alone, assuming the
correctness of the percentages of gold, silver, and copper given on the
cylinder reported by Desroches-Noblecourt to be in the Louvre, as being 75%,
22%, 3%, respectively, (7) would value at $186,648,000 (166,650 lbs. at
approximately $70.00 to the fine ounce), having a buying power infinitely
greater than in today.
Skilfully used as the basis of a pyramid of ledger
credit page entry money, it would be sufficient to maintain the finances of
great enterprise, if not of kingdoms. Lydia, peasant kingdom that had
emerged from the ruins of Phrygia after the Cimmerian invasion, (8) could
very well have functioned in its institution in a similar manner to
Switzerland during the last few hundred years; somewhat in the nature of a
bullion broker's or international banker's refuge. (9)
Which might account,
perhaps, for the ferocity of the destruction by Cyrus of the hapless
Croesus, who was said to have been flayed alive; as example no doubt to
other kings, and to remind them that while their power was national, there
was another power which was international; above and beyond the power of
petty kings...
Similarly, the other metals, copper, bronze, and iron, no longer deemed
precious, and which therefore were often left on the battlefield, would fall
into the hands of members of those semi-criminal castes such as Sadyattes,
previously mentioned, who would control the camp followers that stripped the
dead and thus garnered this scrap metal. These metals offered considerable
profit by way of manufacturing counterfeits of the currencies of those
states wherein base metal currencies were used...
Many Northern states and cities to which considerable industry was being
transferred, used copper or iron fiduciary currencies in earlier times. Such
was the iron currency of Clazomenae mentioned by Aristotle (10) and the iron
spits of Pre-Pheidon Argos, examples of which were dedicated to the Goddess
in the Temple of Hera at Argos at the commencement of silver coinage by
Pheidon, and were actually exhumed from the place of their dedication by the
archaeologists who explored that site. (11)
Herein would have been fertile
field for profit for those that dealt in money in Greece or elsewhere, for
that matter.
Though the Greek himself obviously must have been the foundation of Greek
industry, the Aramean or the Phoenician, bringing the ways of money and
banking and who brought an alphabet and writing to Greece, became the
cornerstone of that industry.
He also brought agencies from the great
banking houses of Babylonia such as that firm mentioned by Professor Sayce
in Babylonian Literature, which flourished from the reign of Nabopolassar,
the father of Nebuchadnezzar, to the reign of Darius Hystaspes;
approximately one hundred years; and of which evidence remains in the clay
cheques and deeds found by some Arabs in a great earthen jar. (12)
Since the
time of Professor Sayce, which is nearly a hundred years ago, much more
evidence of the existence of powerful banking and merchant institutions has
come to light; outstandingly those of the Egibi Sons, and the Murassu, who,
according to Professor Humphrey Michell in his work, The Economics of
Ancient Greece (P. 334), carried on very large and complicated business;
even by modern standards.
Just as Babylonian business and banking houses maintained extensive branches
in the Sumerian cities, such as at Lagash where their records were found to
exceed the records of the king, (13) so it may safely be assumed that they
maintained branches within any state within the limits of the communications
of the day, and where profit was to be made.
The sturdy intelligent people of Greece were a fertile field for the renewal
of industry and trade after the disturbance that must have followed the rise
in prices deriving from the augmentation of precious metal reserves
resulting from the flow of Assyrian plunder on to the bullion markets, and
later, with Babylonia once again supreme following the victories of
Nabopolassar in 605 B.C., from the similar flow of Babylonian plunder.
At
the same time Greece was a place of refuge from the war clouds drifting over
all that Near East world, and the stench of slaughter that followed the
warring hosts...
It would not be long before the skill of the Aramean at letters, money,
counterfeit or otherwise, and in organization of industry, stirred the
peasant kingdoms of Greece. Industries rose under the guidance of these
refugees similar to those of their homelands, to be later followed by a
money economy as to the silver standards of Babylonia, and by the systematic
spreading of money madness amongst the landed aristocracy of Greece, thus
separating them from their peoples for whom they had been the hereditary
guides.
For their peoples and their labours had now become but cyphers;
desirable wealth assessed as according to the figures in the banker's book.
The people who drifted into the cities as slave or freeman, and found
employment in the organized manufacturies of these strangers who by now were
calling themselves Greeks, and were by now bearing Greek names, not
unnaturally gave their allegiance to that new hand that seemed to feed them.
Eagerly, just as in today, they drank at the fountain of hatred of their
former masters, who through their sanction of the activities of these "New
Greeks", and connivance with them in respect to the new money system they
set up, betrayed both their people and themselves...
Among the first steps towards the total monetization of the wealth and
labour of the Greek peoples to a precious metal standard controllable by the
great banking houses of Babylonia, was the permitting of the striking of a
silver coinage on the island of Aegina by Pheidon, (14) "progressive" King
of Argos in 680 B.C., similar to the private coinage that was issued in
Lydia prior to Croesus.
"Progressive" King of Argos meant in this case a
king ready to listen to the blandishments of money power, luring him into
that trap which was the use of precious metal currency, over which he could
have relatively little control; since silver as its base was to be obtained
only at great expense by slave labour at localities too often far distant,
and, relative to localities yielding iron or copper, few and far between.
True, the silver used by the moneyers of Aegina probably came from Laureion,
in sight across the sea. But even though the source of supply was so close
at hand, a coinage of which so small a unit represented so much value,
placed the economy, through the practices of banking, in the hands of the
international bullion controllers.
That the bankers, known as trapezitae, conducted almost the same business as
bankers today is clearly indicated by the article in Seffert's Classical
Dictionary, even if, as the word trapezitae indicates, they but sat at a
bench in the market place, instead of sitting in gilded halls surmounted by
sixty story buildings, as indeed they do today.
Within the limits of clay
tablet and stylus, the same confidence game was operated, though probably
there were few who understood it as being such;... yesterday it was a
conspiracy against the men of a city, or a relatively small state; today a
conspiracy against the whole world.
Those that have their hands on the
throttle of this all embracing evil do not however bear the faintest
resemblance to whole hearted demons in hell, or gods who in their mountain
halls contemptuously plan the total eradication of man who may be their
complete failure.... They are but pudgy and sly little men as much
overwhelmed by the monster they have raised, as are the foolish nations that
permitted them so to do.
Of Ancient Greek banking Seffert says :
"...Bankers were called by the
Greeks trapezitae because they sat at tables in the market places, the
centre of all business transactions. They acted as money changers exchanging
for a commission heavy money or gold into smaller coin, and the moneys of
different systems with each other. In commercial cities they would do a
considerable trade in this way, the different standards and the uncertainty
of the stamping of the coins in Greece creating a great demand for their
assistance.
They also acted as money lenders both on a small and a large
scale. Finally they received money on deposit. People placed their money
with them for safe custody, partly to facilitate the management of it.
The
depositors, according to their convenience, either drew out sums of money
themselves, or commissioned their banker to make payment to a third person.
In this line the business of the banks was considerable. If a citizen had a
large sum of money circulating in business, he probably preferred to put it
in a bank and to hand over to the banker the business of making his
payments.
Strangers too found that the banks offered them such facilities
that they were glad to make considerable use of them. (15) The bankers kept
strict account of all monies in their charge. If a person were making a
payment to another who was a depositor at the same bank, the banker would
simply transfer the requisite sum from one account to another. The bankers
were generally well known from the public character of their occupation, and
they naturally gained great experience in business.
Consequently their
advice and assistance were often asked for in the ordinary affairs of life.
They would be called in to attest the conclusion of contracts, and would
take charge of sums of money, the title to which was disputed, and of
important documents. Business of this kind was generally in the hands of
resident aliens." (16)
The above quotation from the great German scholar, Oskar Seffert, leaves
those of us who understand the origins and meaning of today's banking,
little doubt, as previously pointed out, that within the limits of clay
tablet and stylus, every fraudulent practice known to banking would have
been practiced.
Also the commonly accepted idea that instruments used in
foreign trade, such as Letters of Credit, Bills of Exchange, etc. were a
discovery of the 12th Century A.D., is further clearly proved erroneous by
the sentence:
"Strangers too found that the banks offered them such
facilities that they were glad to make considerable use of them." (17)
Therefore behind the monetary reforms of King Pheidon of Argos we must see
not the wonder of what so many so-called scholars would call the arrival of
the "Invention" of coinage in Greece, but the comings and goings of strange
aliens with letters from mysterious "Important" men who dwelt in Tyre, or
Sidon, or Sardis, or who dwelt in Babylonia itself; everything to be in the
name of "progress", everything to be joy and light!...
The only thing our
poor peasant king had to ask himself was...
"Joy and light for whom... Us or
these panders, pornographers, and luxury pedlars who now flock to our
shores?"
Very soon, no doubt, the answer became apparent.
Behind the Aramaic speaking
banker came the slave trader, and it was not long before the poor people
found that the king's law was no longer for them, and was but a measure
behind which these glib and double talking "Bankers" operated...
"We must
protect the people's savings!"
...no doubt was their cry, yesterday, as in
today.
Such silver coinage as was produced at Aegina or Argos would have been no
more than a few seen symbols, the apex of an inverted pyramid of unseen or
abstract symbols of which only the money master really understood the
meaning and purpose, and only he knew how to manipulate.
Through
manipulation of these "Credits" in relation to the silver that people now
thought was their money, King Pheidon himself could have been tricked into
believing himself a slave because he could not repay his so-called "debt".
However the banker needed the king as such, for a while yet no doubt.
In the meantime peasantry and lesser nobility were drawn into this trap of
irredeemable debt, and, as the king's law had to be upheld, they and their
families would be sold into that cruel slave system that was growing up all
over the Mediterranean world and through which, money economy, now grown
into a very monster, could find docile labour for the dreary grind of the
new methods of semi-mass production in manufacture, such as it had brought
into being, and against which the reforms of Solon as described in the
previous chapter, were directed.
History should not be misled by the Greek names of those significant figures
and families concerned with money and money power at that time, whether in
Lydia or in Greece...
Oskar Seffert states quite clearly that the bankers or
trapezitae were resident aliens. (18) Controlling the undercurrents of city
life as undoubtedly they would have so done, in those days it would have
been no more difficult than it is in these days to secure the services of a
front man to promote their interests, and secure them citizenship if
necessary.
Just as aliens who seek trade and power amongst whatever people
they maybe, so often change their names to suit the circumstances while
retaining allegiance to that group into which they were born, so it was in
that day, nearly three thousand years ago. In the early days of the Greek
cities, citizenship was easy to obtain and persons with pretence at power,
influence and money, in a society where worship of money had replaced
worship of the gods, in truth, would have no great difficulty in that
direction.
Out of the weakening of what was left of the true power of kingly rule at
Athens, such as descended from Mycenaean Greece, and consequent growth of
"Aristocratic" democracy, doubtless deriving from concession to
international money power for its assistance against the Dorian previous to
1100 B.C., and before whom it appears the city of Athens never fell, came
the replacement of the title Wanax indicating god-king reigning in earthly
splendor, for that of Archon-Basileus of lesser degree. (19)
Out of the
further weakening of such aristocracy of the Greeks as later existed,
whether Achaean, Ionian, or Dorian, and the soul destruction sown amongst
them as consequence of their betrayal into slavery and abuse of their
followers who had so trusted them and looked to them for guidance, derived
those conditions out of which the so-called tyrant rose to power.
Out of the
involvement of the natural leaders of the people (20) with things ignoble
and inimical to their own kind, such as trade and "Money-making", and with
strange luxuries and vices, rose those men, often traitors to their own
class, who fronted for the conspiratorial money power of the age...
Such
men steered the restless aspirations of the wage slaves of the cities; those
dispossessed masses so easily stirred to active resentment against their
former leaders deriving from the ancient nobility; and who, of course, had
no more understanding than themselves of that force by which they were both
being manipulated...
References
1. "But I perhaps, owing to the number of advocates may be classed in the
common body; the battle of Cannae has made you a sufficiently respectable
accuser. We have seen many men slain, not at Trasimene but at Servilius. Who
was not wounded there with Phrygian steel ?..." Cicero: Orationes, "Pro S.
Roscius" (Vol. I, P. 65; C.D. Yonge; London, 1883.).
2. Kenneth Pearson: The Dorak Affair, London, 1967.
3. Strabo, XIII, iv, 5. (Del Mar: History of the Precious Metals, P. 51.)
4. Christopher Dawson: Age of the Gods, P. 295.
5. James H. Breasted: History of Egypt, P. 281.
6. Ibid. P. 559.
7. Christiane Desroches-Noblecourt: Tutankhamen, P. 33. New York, 1963.
8. Encyclopaedia of World History, P. 37, Boston, 1948.
9. The fact that after the destruction of Croesus by Cyrus, 547 B.C., Sardis
remained the principal mint for the whole Persian Empire, and for which it
turned out Sigloi as to the Babylonian standard, gives further strength to
the idea.
10. Frederick William Madden, M.R.A.S.: Coins of the Jews, P.29; London;
1881.
11. Charles Seltsman: Greek Coins, pp. 34-35.
12. Frederick William Madden, M.R.A.S.: Coins of the Jews, P. 6. (footnote).
13. Cambridge Ancient History, P. 392, Vol. 1.
14. According to the table on P. 35, "Greek Coins" by C. Seltsman, the
Aeginetan drachma was established without any doubt at its given standard,
because in the time of Pheidon, the ratio of silver to iron was 400:1. He
clearly had been advised to establish the new silver drachmas and obolos so
that they would have the same purchasing power as the now discarded iron
obolos and "Drax"...... according to their valuation in an International
market where money was metal by weight.
15. Obviously for discounting Bills of Exchange, raising money against Bills
of Lading, Warehouse Receipts, and the realization into that which
circulated as money of the promissory note issued as between friends or
otherwise.
16. Oskar Seffert: Dictionary of Classical Antiquities, P. 91.
17. Visiting Merchants and Ships' Captains.
18. Oskar Seffert: Dictionary of Classical Antiquities, P. 91.
19. Jacquetta Hawkes: Dawn of the Gods, P. 262; New York; 1968.
20. Referring to the Hellenic terminology in connection with banking
transactions and professions etc. Professor Heichelheim of vast scholarship
recorded "That the banking transactions of the individual bankers, money
lenders, and debtors influenced the whole economic life and even, to a
certain degree, the intellectual development in Attica, the territories of
the Delian League and in many other polis territories of our period, since
the fifth, if not occasionally sixth centuries B.C. will be obvious from the
above list which has a surprising number of specializations..." Fritz
Heichelheim: An Ancient Economic History, Vol. II, pp. 196-197; Leyden;
1958-1970.
Back to Contents